Clayton Christensen's book, The Innovator’s Dilemma: When
New Technologies Cause Great Firms to Fail may have been read by more college
and university administrators than any other business book of the last decade.
It is easy to understand why, because there are some obvious parallels between
the great firms that fail, and research universities.
Christensen looks at a very large set of corporations that
were on everyone’s list of best run companies, leaders in their industry, that
then lost their footing and in a very short time either disappeared or became
almost irrelevant in their industry. He
found that these companies failed because the management did a great job of
analyzing their existing market, responded to the expressed desires of that
market, and effectively allocated their investments to projects with the best
return. They were so successful in
handling the present that they were unable to see that innovations were
occurring at the fringes of their industry that had the potential to completely
restructure it.
Christensen introduces the key concepts of sustaining and disruptive
technologies. (It should be noted that
he uses “technology” as a short-hand for both technology and business model.) Sustaining technologies are new technologies
that enable the improvement of existing products along dimensions that
traditionally have been valued by mainstream customers. Disruptive technologies, on the other hand,
in the near term lead to worse product performance according to traditional
quality metrics. However, these new
technologies have some characteristics that are not found in the dominant
technology, characteristics that appeal to some customers at the fringe of the
industry. Thus products using this new
disruptive technology will initially perform less well than existing products
on the metrics most appreciated by most customers, but will bring new
attributes such as low cost, small size, or convenience that are sufficiently
important to a small segment of the market that they are willing to forego some
performance in order to get them. Often,
the dominant firms are happy to give up these customers because the products
they really wanted, being out of the mainstream, brought in lower profits.
However, technology can improve rapidly. So long as there is some customer base, there
are resources to continue developing the disruptive technology. At some point, the disruptive technology
improves sufficiently in the characteristics valued by the main market that it
becomes competitive in that market with the existing technology. However, the disruptive technology also has
the additional useful characteristics that enabled it to find its original
market, and lower cost is usually one of those characteristics. At this point,
the disruptive technology becomes more desirable to the mainstream market than
is the traditional technology, and the value metrics of the field change
rapidly towards the new technology. Mainstream customers demand products built
with the disruptive technology, and in a relatively brief time the traditional
technology and the companies that were wedded to that technology disappear or
become marginal.
Christensen discusses in detail the difficulties that
established companies have in embracing a new disruptive technology. Few are able to do so, and so sink into
relative irrelevancy or bankruptcy. Part
of the problem is just the desire to hold onto a highly profitable strategy as
long as possible. Small but growing markets
cannot generate sufficient profits to satisfy growth needs of large
companies. Another problem is that the
entire established company was structured around making the original product,
which had a huge market and was probably larger, more expensive, more complex
than the new product. The corporate infrastructure
and cost structure, from factories to administration, was inappropriate to
follow a radically different model where the market was small but growing, and
the product might be very different from the existing product in size,
complexity, and cost. In addition, market research on markets that don’t exist
is not really possible. As a result, the traditional companies were unable to
convince themselves following accepted “good management” approaches that there
would be a large market for the disruptive product.
The apparent parallels between conditions in higher
education and the industries discussed by Christensen are disquietingly obvious,
and explain why so many university administrators bought copies of this book to
give their colleagues. Traditional colleges
and universities control most of the market, using techniques and value
propositions that most often date back centuries. However, innovation is
occurring at the fringes. Technology breakthroughs
of the last decade have enabled potentially powerful web-facilitated,
technology-enhanced distance learning. Numerous for-profit institutions of higher learning have started up, or greatly
extended their existing programs, using both distance learning and
brick-and-mortar approaches. On the non-profit side, some non-traditional
models such as the Open University have been growing rapidly in acceptance. In almost all cases, the response of
traditional higher education has been that these approaches are inferior to
what we have been doing, suitable only for students of the type that we are not
terribly interested in serving. Yet one
can see that in many ways a number of these non-traditional institutions have,
indeed, improved significantly over time according to our mainstream metrics,
just as would be predicted by Christensen.
Perhaps the greatest new disruptive attribute that the model
of the new competitors brings is convenience for, and service to, the
students. Classes are taught at multiple
sites and on schedules chosen for convenience for students, or are offered 24/7
on the web. The rigidity of the
semester system has been jettisoned in many cases, and students can follow
courses year round in order to speed up their education. Considerable attention
is paid in the best of these to student placement (including having panels of
potential employers helping to define educational needs) and advising. In the best, considerable attention is also paid
to teacher performance, and poor teachers are rotated out rapidly. New courses
are quickly brought on line in response to changing demand. Some few of these
institutions are using the results of cognitive learning theories to structure
their courses in order to improve learning – something that would be quite
unusual in most research universities. The
education has become learner-, rather than teacher-centered.
Another important disruptive attribute is low cost and
scalability. I wrote in For Profit and/or Non-Profit future, Feb.20, 2006 and Competitive Higher Education,
March 3, 2006, about the research university’s interlocking
missions of research, teaching, and social development of its students. The new competitors pick off only one of
these missions, teaching, dropping off the very expensive components of
research and social development of students ( this latter has led us to build
and support residence halls, fancy gymnasiums, dining facilities, intramural
sports, football teams, etc.). As a
consequence, the new competitors generally need only teaching facilities (with
administrative facilities somewhere, but most often centralized and not tied
geographically to the teaching facilities), and these they often rent. Faculty are not research oriented, and thus
move in a much less expensive competitive market than the faculty who are hired
at research universities. These faculty essentially
are never tenured, and thus the size and specialties of the faculty can easily
be changed in response to student demands in order to minimize costs and
maximize profits. Because courses are
usually designed centrally and used at multiple sites, additional students can
be taught with minimal marginal cost. Where distance learning is used extensively, scalability is even more
evident.
So is this a new disruptive model that will wipe out
traditional research universities? There
are reasons to believe the results will not be that cataclysmic. There are “moats” that protect research
universities to some degree, as I discuss in Competitive Higher Education, March 2, 2006. Among the most enduring of
these is the credentialing power of an established, high reputation university.
Also, as I point out in How about distance learning ?, March 3, 2006, distance learning itself can be both a
sustaining and disruptive technology. It is sustaining because it enables us to
improve upon our educational product. It becomes disruptive if it exacerbates
the winner-take-all (Robert Frank and Philip Cook, the Winner-Take-All Society
) tendencies of higher education. It is
also potentially disruptive because it changes the power relationship within
universities because it greatly increases student options. The greatest disruptive risk, in my opinion,
comes from the political arena. As we
move more into a market-state (Welcome to the Market-State, Feb.20 ,2006), government will be looking much more
closely at the impact of its support of higher education. As our competitors move up in quality, their
lower cost will be quite attractive to legislators who want to be able to claim
credit for having made higher education accessible to all. We then will see a number of legislative
changes that serve to “level the playing field”, as in forcing acceptance of
transfer credits and opening up accessibility to federal student funds. Ultimately, the government could question
whether the high cost integrated research university is the least expensive
model to achieve the goals of research and teaching.
If the new models are disruptive, can we embrace them more
effectively than the corporations Christensen studied? Although any major change is difficult for
universities, we are benefited in this instance by not having a profit
motive. As Christensen shows, much of
the difficulty for corporations in making change relates to the necessity to
keep growing in profit, which discourages attention to any venture that has a
low profit margin. For better or for
worse, we have lots of ventures that have a “low profit margin” – think of
Classics. However, we have our own
obstacles to change that corporation’s lack. To really turn to a more learner-centered approach will require major
changes in university culture (I will talk more about learner-centered
education in a later post). Simply
changing away from our rigid semester or quarter system will be difficult
enough. We also do not have a tradition of strong cost-cutting of the type that
corporations have had to embrace over the past decades, and our inability to
keep our expense differential from continuing to widen will eventually cause
problems with parents and politicians.
As we go forward, the outcomes described by Christensen give
us reason to avoid overconfidence, and his ideas give us a useful structure for
analysis.
Comments
You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.