How would a transition to a Market-State (Welcome to the
Market-State, Feb.20, 2006) manifest itself in higher education? Two quotes capture a good part of the core
meaning of such a transition. The first
comes from James Duderstadt, the former President of the University of Michigan, in “The Future of
Higher Education in the Knowledge-Driven, Global Economy of the 21st
Century”:
“It is important to remember that most of our institutions
were the result of public policy and public investment through actions of
governments at the national and regional level. …Yet today, in the United States and many other nations, public leaders
are increasingly discarding public policy in favor of market forces to
determine priorities for social investment.”
The second comes from a Commonwealth of Learning/UNESCO report written by Robin
Middlehurst and Steve Woodfield “The Role of Transnational, Private, and
For-Profit Provision in Meeting Global Demand for Tertiary Education: Mapping,
Regulation and Impact"(p.6):
“The tertiary education context in which students,
providers, and national Governments now operate, is changing rapidly as a
result of demographic trends, the complex effects of globalization on economies
and societies, and a shift in the role of Government in public services – from
provider, to facilitator, regulator, and partner.”
As Bobbitt suggests, the role of government is increasingly
changing its focus from providing for the welfare of its citizens, to
regulating the market in such a way as to increase individual opportunity. Bobbitt defines three types of
Market-State: Entrepreneurial (e.g.USA),
Mercantile (e.g. much of Asia), and Managerial (e.g.Europe). Within the Entrepreneurial state, the
government takes the most non-interventionist approach in many realms. In particular, low taxes are a key component
of this model. This means that the
government has even fewer resources to allocate to social investment, and the
market must play an even larger role in addressing a large number of
issues.
There are many ways in which a transition to a
Market-State might be manifested in higher education. I want
to focus here on one of those - how higher education is viewed by the general public and politicians. After WWII,
higher education generally was viewed as providing a public good. That is, educated people were sufficiently
important in moving the country forward across such a broad spectrum of
activities that societal support of their education was justified. The role of Vannaver Bush in articulating
this role is discussed in Metrics of Academic Excellence in the 21st
Century, Feb. 27, 2006. However, as income differentials began to
grow between those with only a high school diploma and those with a college
degree, it became clear that there was considerable personal benefit to higher
education as well. Over time, in an
atmosphere that is charged with the forces building the Market-State, the
American public has come to view higher education as primarily a private good rather
than a public good. Indeed, a recent
survey carried out by the Chronicle of Higher Education found that a sizable
majority of Americans now feel that higher education should be paid for by parents
and students, rather than government.
Bobbitt emphasized when he visited USC that the dynamics of the Market-State alone do not determine whether education will be viewed as a public or a private good. However, if one reads Bobbitt's description of the entrepreneural form of the Market-State, one can see that there is a strong push in this form towards the private good position. In addition, the aging electorate may well play a strong role in this shift of attitude.
It light of all this, we can look at some of the recent
congressional discussions and outcomes regarding higher education. One should always be wary of attributing a
legislative outcome to a single driver (politics is politics, after all), but
there is a certain consistency to recent events when viewed from the
perspective of a transition to an Entrepreneurial Market-State in which tax
revenues have been lowered as a matter of policy.
If higher education has become a private good, then
increased student aid should not have a high priority in competition for scarce
public resources. Thus, it is not surprising
that we see Pell grants flat, and federal loan programs shrinking. Similarly, it is not surprising that state
support for higher education generally has been declining, forcing students and
their families to pay a greater share of educational costs through higher
tuition or fees. On the other hand,
access to opportunity is a characteristic of the Market-State. Access, therefore, must be encouraged with as
little cost to the State as is possible. Increasing access at no cost to the government
could be viewed as a driver behind recent congressional proposals to limit
tuition growth. In a market state,
competition is good, and likely to increase capacity and hold down costs. So another low cost way to increase access is
to increase competition. Making it more
difficult for an institution to deny credits from another institution helps to
blur quality differentials, thus increasing competition. Mandatory standardized testing for all college
students is a way to increase comparative information to consumers and thereby
increase competition. Similarly, competition and access are increased by opening
up federal financial aid to students of for-profit colleges and colleges that
teach primarily by distance education. These certainly will not be the last
proposals (or laws) of this type that we will see.
In Competitive Higher Education,March 3, 2006, I wrote about the difficulty in
measuring quality in higher education. This difficulty lead to a number of rather expensive surrogates being
used for quality, and the ensemble of surrogates (and their cost) helped to
build a protective moat around research universities. Most of the
proposals mentioned above aim directly at the question of quality. Some imply that quality doesn’t matter (e.g. all
course credits are equal), others seek to impose standards of quality that are
unlikely to be designed to recognize the special attributes of education in a
research university (e.g.mandatory standardized testing). All have the effect of "leveling the playing field" of higher education, thus helping
to drain the moat that has provided such stability to the university over the past century.
Comments
You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post.